BLOGS WEBSITE

The Basin Plan, its implementation, its enforcement & cotton

chowilla regulator

David AdamsonDr. David Adamson, ARC DECRA fellow at The Centre for Global Food and Resources, shares his thoughts on the Basin Plan, its implementation, its enforcement and cotton.

Well the 4 Corners report has gotten things interesting around the office.

I’m going to start with the easiest thing first, cotton. Australian agriculture is not restricted by land, it is restricted by water. The Murray-Darling Basin (MDB) is 1 million km2, about 80% of the MDB is dedicated to agriculture and irrigation is less than 2% of that area. (Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS), 2008). The argument that ‘cotton is a thirsty crop’ is a complete red herring. Cotton is an annual crop that is ideal to plant, as it provides the best $/ML from its use, especially in areas where there is little to no water security on an annual basis (i.e., no guarantee of supply so you either have water or you don’t). If you forbid farmers to plant cotton, they will use the same amount of water producing a crop with a lower $/ML return. All you do is make the irrigator earn less money. The real argument is and always will be is how much water should different groups (irrigators, other rural uses, urban supplies, the environment, and other water users) have.

Now let’s define water property rights. Property rights define who can access and use a given resource [read (Quiggin, 1986)]. The ownership of rights allows individuals to make money.  But to be effective the right must be enforced. Water entitlements are property rights that provide an irrigator the ability to access water. In the MDB, water entitlements can be divided into three right structures with decreasing reliability, high security, general security and supplementary. The Barwon-Darling is basically supplementary rights where it’s a use it or lose it mentality, as there is little public storage, hence the large dams. In many years, the face value of that water entitlement is never delivered.

The Plan follows the concepts of common property (Ciriacy-Wantrup and Bishop, 1975). Where to deal with an overall allocation of water in a closed basin (i.e. there are no new water rights to be had), and the externalities caused by that use (e.g. salinity), a quantum of water rights is transferred from private users (i.e. irrigators) to a ‘trustee’ (i.e. Commonwealth Water Entitlement Holder) to manage that ‘environmental’ water in the national interest.  By restricting the volume that irrigators have, and giving water to the environment, the environments health improves and the extra water flowing in the river, improves the quality of asset (i.e. water quality improves via dilution) and everyone benefits from that..

The fundamental design of the plan is good. The implementation of the plan has a number of shortcomings and that is discussed in the recent submission (here).

What 4 Corners discovered last night is allegedly, that the monitoring of water extractions and enforcement of property rights has failed in NSW. Additionally there may have been collusion and the sharing of public information to a select few. This creates information asymmetry and subsequently power in the market. The fallout from this allegation will be the interesting part.

The allegation of the volume of water being taken (1.19 GL, need to know if this is a single or multiple years), should have had those responsible for managing the flow scratching their heads as to why water was not reaching expected destinations. Presently there is insufficient information to know exactly if or how this was followed up.

The Basin Plan was designed in the national interest, so one would assume that the response should be federal. But part of this is also derived from the failure of the federal government in not ensuring that monitoring was occurring. I think the loss of the National Water Commission and the transferring of their data collection to others was an oversight.

  • Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS), 2008. Water and the Murray-Darling Basin – A Statistical Profile Australia 2000–01 to 2005–06: ABS Catalogue No. 4610.0.55.007, in: Statistics, A.B.o. (Ed.), ABS Catalogue No. 4610.0.55.007, Canberra, Australia.
  • Ciriacy-Wantrup, S.V., Bishop, R.C., 1975. “Common Property” as a Concept in Natural Resources Policy. Natural Resources Journal 15, 713-721.
  • Quiggin, J., 1986. Common Property, Private Property and Regulation The Case Of Dryland Salinity. Australian Journal of Agricultural Economics 30, 103-117.

This post was originally published on Dr Adamson’s blog, where you can read more about his research.

This entry was posted in Current issues, Water policy. Bookmark the permalink.
 

Comments are closed.