BLOGS WEBSITE

The election showed the electorate is fractious and demanding. With narrow-interest parties now elected to parliament, policymaking in pursuit of the long-term national interest is going to be challenging, if not problematic. This comes at a time when the need for Australia to adjust to more-difficult times has become even more pressing.

In the background to this election, Australia’s prosperity has switched from rapid growth to decline. Australians enjoyed very strong growth in living standards from the mid-1990s through to the early 2010s. National income per capita rose $27 500 (after inflation) over the 18 years to 2011-12, compared with $9 500 over the 18 years to 1993-94. Since 2011-12, however, national income per capita has fallen at least $2000 (the latest available annual data go as far as 2014-15).

To see what is needed to stem the fall and then return to rising living standards, it is important to understand what brought on the good times and what brought on the decline.

A surge in productivity growth was the main source of stronger growth in living standards in the 1990s and early 2000s. GDP per hour worked – a broad measure of labour productivity – accounted for 70 per cent of the $14 500 increase in national income per capita between 1993-94 and 2003-04.

The productivity surge meant that production of goods and services could be ramped up to meet stronger growth in demand without creating labour shortages and cost pressures. Because whatever was produced was in demand, the additional production also generated more income and that in turn meant more wage growth and more income per adult and child in the population.

The strong growth in living standards over the rest of the 2000s came from a different source. A very strong and prolonged lift in the terms of trade – the ratio of export prices to import prices – accounted for half of the $13 000 growth in average income between 2003-04 and 2011-12. At the same time, productivity growth slowed from its earlier rate.

A terms of trade rise does not require more production to generate more real income – just that sales on export markets bring more revenue. That’s where the prices part of the mining boom came in. Cheaper import prices, on the other hand, meant Australians’ incomes went further – for example, on cheaper motor vehicles, petrol, household goods and overseas holidays.

The fall in living standards since 2011-12 has been due to a sharp fall in the terms of trade. Think of the fall in mining commodity prices as lowering export prices, while the fall in the exchange rate has raised import prices.

Rising average living standards do not automatically raise the circumstances of all people equally or proportionately. But they do provide the wherewithal to pursue social programs, as well as environmental protection and ‘nation building’ infrastructure development. For example, continuing strong growth in living standards in the 2000s allowed boosts to welfare, subsidies to childcare and moves to reduce carbon emissions. There were also increases in private spending and large investments in ports, desalination plants, renewable energy, electricity and communications distribution networks, education and defence.

So rising living standards are important, not only in determining how well off we are but also in helping to implement broader national objectives.

Crucially, since the terms of trade are outside of our control, the best way to get back to rising living standards is to restore strong productivity growth.

That has not yet happened.

The task is very challenging. If stronger productivity growth can be secured in the short run, it would help to counteract the effects of falling terms of trade. But we need productivity growth at least as strong as the record-high rates of the 1990s to achieve even moderate improvements in our living standards.

Yet there was hardly a whisper about productivity during the election campaign. True, the major parties could point to a policy or two that would have some influence on productivity at some time. But they hardly did service to the three policy ‘C’s that are required — comprehensiveness, consistency and commitment.

There is no single ‘silver bullet’ way to improve productivity performance at the national level. Productivity operates in a complex, multidimensional way. Implementation of many, sometimes small, measures are needed. That is, a comprehensive policy approach is required.

Policies need to be implemented consistently. If governments talk the productivity talk for some firms and industries but then insulate another firm or industry from market pressures, it creates incentives for firms to relax on their own efforts to improve productivity and to also seek favourable treatment from governments in order to secure their market position. Unless there is a market failure and the ‘softest’ correcting intervention is used, it is usually safe to presume that selective government intervention reduces national productivity.

Commitment means that productivity gets high priority in consideration of all policies. The question of what each policy means for national productivity and when and how it will take effect needs to be addressed. That does not mean productivity has to be absolutely paramount in all cases. But it does mean that, if the nation is to forego income by holding back on productivity, we need to know we get something more valuable in return.

In the electorate, some perceive that globalisation is too disruptive and the economic trends work for the rich and not the ordinary person. They want protection – income, job and industry protection – but see governments as prioritising other causes rather than giving them the surety and relief they want. However, to some extent at least, their difficulties are really manifestations of falling living standards – lower wage increases combined with higher living costs due to infrastructure decisions, particularly in power and water, when the times were good.

Many in the electorate continue with demands on governments as though the good times keep rolling on. They call for more government spending in areas of health, education and infrastructure and for more government intervention to protect the environment. However, the harsh reality is that, as a nation, we have to focus on generating more income, reduce spending and reprioritise different areas of spending.

I hesitate to nominate particular areas for attention in order to improve national productivity. As stated above, a comprehensive approach is needed. Nevertheless, more systematic attention should be put on productivity in the public sector and, in particular, on productivity in the health and education sectors. This would hopefully turn some attention away from the dominant focus on size of expenditures toward assessments of the outcomes these sectors achieve with the resources we devote to them. That is, we look at value for money, not just money spent.

With a fractious electorate and narrow-interest parties in parliament, there is a clear need for politicians to engage the community in a much broader debate about Australia’s economic outlook and thereby strive for general acceptance that choices and efforts need to be made. Policymaking also needs to be underpinned by evidence, public scrutiny and transparency about the judgements and compromises made.

Hopefully, we can get to a point where the political debate is more about which party is going to do more to raise productivity, lift living standards and ensure the nation gets better value — not just who is going to spend more or cut more in particular areas.

Dean Parham worked for the Productivity Commission until 2008, leading a program of research on Australia’s productivity performance. He is an alumnus of the University of Adelaide and is currently a non-resident Research Fellow in its School of Economics. email: dean@deanparham.com

 

Posted in Business economics, Economic growth, Public policy
Leave a comment

“Citizens’ jury questions economics of nuke dump” is the headline to Rebecca Puddy’s article on page 2 of The Australian on Monday 11 July, 2016. Ms Puddy’s article begins: “The bid to establish a nuclear waste facility in South Australia has suffered a further setback, after an independent “citizens’ jury” raised concerns about the economic viability of the project.…after hearing from experts, the jury questioned the economic underpinnings of the [nuclear royal] commission’s findings.” Daniel Wills, State Political Editor of The Advertiser, wrote an article (“Nuclear jury calls for more rigorous information”) on the same day in which he said: “A citizens’ jury of 54 people has called for closer analysis of the business case underpinning a proposed nuclear waste dump in SA…” (The Advertiser, 11 July, 2016, p.4).

I attended the citizens’ jury’s deliberations on Saturday 9 July, as an expert witness. This was principally as a result of my articles opposing the dump in my Tuesday column in In Daily. There was one other expert economics witness questioning the economics of the dump: Rod Campbell, Research Director of the Australia Institute in Canberra. Several of the expert witnesses supporting the economics of the dump had been involved in undertaking the economic/financial analysis of the dump for the Royal Commission.

The Jury operated as a free-flowing discussion rather than with set pieces presented by the witnesses followed by questions from the jurors. The issues are difficult and technical. But the jurors were great. They made me think that if I am ever in deep trouble with the law, I will always opt for trial by jury.

My fellow citizens on the jury were sensible, common-sense, people, who could see that the proposed dump was not a business proposition (as described in the Royal Commission’s prospectus) that any sensible person would invest in. They quite properly insisted that the business prospectus for the dump should be made watertight – or the dump abandoned.

Pertinent questions various jurors asked included:

  • What is the Royal Commission’s guesstimate of the value of the dump based on?
  • Are we factoring in new technology? [The proposed project lasts for 120 years.]
  • Are we burying a lost opportunity if future value is identified in the waste? [For example, to be used as fuel in 4th generation nuclear power stations.]
  • Who takes accountability for managing the storage facility?
  • How can the Net Present Value of the dump be presented in a language that a common person can understand?
  • How do we quantify the benefit economically of the proposed nuclear storage facility? How robust are the assumptions in the Royal Commission’s Report?
  • Is the proposal purely for the money? What else could the State do?
  • What will the dump really cost? [Having the new Royal Adelaide Hospital in mind]
  • How much would we be able to sell the dump for?
  • If the Royal Commission’s dump proposal was floated as a business in the United States, would you buy shares in it? What would need to be done to make you willing to buy shares in it?

I led off my remarks by asking the question: “Does the nuclear dump proposition presented in the Royal Commission’s Report stack up as a business? Would you put your money into it?” I then quoted South Australian Treasurer, Tom Koutsantonis’s Budget Speech to State Parliament on 7 July:

“Mr Speaker, there is no single measure or silver bullet that will address the challenges our state currently faces, not Olympic Dam or the future submarines, not Arrium nor the nuclear Royal Commission. But tax cuts are key, innovation is important, education is vital, health is essential and infrastructure is critical.”

Later, I noted that, in the 1980s, at the personal request of Premier John Bannon, I had led the team that put together the State’s bid for the Multi-Function Polis – which we won in competition against the other States. The Commonwealth’s assessment team said to me when they interviewed me that they had never seen such a brilliant exercise in rubbery figures. But they awarded the MFP to us, anyway. Our rubbery figures were better than the other State’s rubbery figures! Eventually the Japanese abandoned the project and we were left with the Gillman site (as well as Mawson Lakes, of course).

I also noted that the State Bank collapsed financially because it took on excessive risks to grow very rapidly, until its bad debts overwhelmed it. Premier Bannon had felt that this aggressive growth strategy would assist the State’s economy (the Government owned the Bank) by increasing the dividend flow to the Government. It didn’t. It cost the State a lot.

I could have added that I own shares in a company that, some time ago, I paid about $1 each for (in round numbers), that had a splendidly green and lucrative plan to generate electricity from hot rocks in the Cooper Basin. The project hit severe, unexpected and unusual difficulties in pursuing this attractive and worthwhile objective. The shares have now lost a great deal of their value and the company is principally engaged in other electricity generating activities.

There were other points I could have made. For example, the price ($1.75million/tonne of heavy metal) that we are expected to receive for accepting dumped waste in the Royal Commission’s economic analysis is very high relative to the costs of constructing such dumps in Finland ($0.65million/tonne of heavy metal) and Sweden ($1.13million/tonne of heavy metal) (and elsewhere, presumably, like South Africa, Mexico, and so on). This price seems to be based on an avoided cost scenario. The price is a guess. There is no market price for accepting dumped waste at the present time. The Royal Commission’s analysis does not envision that a competitive market could emerge, which would cut the projected price significantly.

The cost of shipping the waste seems to be a notional allowance ($0.20m/tonne heavy metal). Where this comes from is not obvious. South Australia is assumed by the Royal Commission to get 50% of the accessible world market for waste nuclear fuel. This is a very big share. It is based simply on an assumption, not on fact. The prices, costs and quantities have to be known over the 120 years that the project will last. This is a very tall order, as the wild swings in prices in commodity markets show. The risks that the assumptions will be incorrect are substantial.

Hence, far from being a financial bonanza, as proposed by the Royal Commission, the project could make minimal returns, and be a real distraction from alternative paths to the economic future of the State based on our skills, our innovative capabilities and our capacity for hard work. These are our real strengths; not gambling on finding an easy way out of our present financial difficulties. As Mr Koutsantonis said in his Budget Speech – there is no silver bullet.

Dick Blandy is a contributor to the Adelaide Economic Policy Forum

In the interests of disclosure, one of the Adelaide Economic Policy Forum’s other contributors (Paul Kerin) was a Member of the Socio-Economic Modelling Committee that advised the Royal Commission and was also an expert witness on economics at the Citizens Jury proceedings. While Dick and Paul usually agree on most issues, they have different views on this one!

More information on the Citizens Jury is available at: http://yoursay.sa.gov.au/initiatives/citizens-jury

 

 

 

Posted in Business economics, Dick Blandy, Economic growth, Public policy, South Australian economy
Leave a comment

In an article in today’s Australian, I expand on the argument I made on the Adelaide Economic Policy Forum article last Monday (available here) that unless one party can form a majority Federal government, it would be in the public interest to go back to the polls. The key point is that a majority government (regardless of which major party forms it) would reduce policy and other key uncertainties and thereby encourage investment and consumption spending, resulting in higher  economic growth. Today’s Australian article, titled “Let’s have another vote to end uncertainty”, is available here.

Posted in Business economics, Economic growth, Economic research, Paul Kerin, Public policy
Leave a comment

Bill Carmichael, the legendary former Chairman of the Industries Assistance Commission, was a very influential figure behind major economic reforms that have delivered substantial benefits to Australia. We are delighted that Bill has submitted an important paper titled Governance arrangements for future trade negotiations to the Adelaide Economic Policy Forum. Bill’s paper is about the […]

Posted in Economic growth, Economic reform, International trade, Public policy
Leave a comment

As we move into the post-Federal-election period, there is continuing debate about where growth will come from and what voters thought of the pitches on this question made by the various parties. Data always helps these debates and here’s an example. This is a story about exports – and services exports in particular. An article […]

Posted in Business economics, Christopher Findlay, Economic growth, Economic research, Public policy, South Australian Centre for Economic Studies
Leave a comment

In my January column in Company Director, titled “The election effect” (and available here), I pointed out that economic research shows that in the year leading up to an election, business investment is (on average) about 5% lower than it otherwise would be. As business investment accounts for about 15% of GDP, a typical election […]

Posted in Business economics, Economic growth, Economic research, Paul Kerin, Public policy, South Australian economy
Leave a comment

Outside the monetarist and free-marketeer camps, few UK economists advocated Brexit (the few notable exceptions included Cardiff University’s Patrick Minford). In fact, the UK’s most prominent independent economic research centres – the National Institute of Economic and Social Research, the Institute for Fiscal Studies and the Centre for Economic Performance – went as far as […]

Posted in Andreas Cebulla, Economic reform, International trade, Public policy, South Australian Centre for Economic Studies
Leave a comment

Two University of Adelaide experts – Director of the EU Centre for Global Affairs Jane Drake-Brockman and Jane Drake-Brockman and the Regional Director (Southeast Asia) of the Institute for International Trade’s Centre for Economic Studies Associate Professor Shandre Thangavelu – have commented on the implications of Brexit for Australia and other Asia-Pacific nations regarding free trade negotiations […]

Posted in Institue for International trade, International trade, Public policy, Shandre Thangavelu
Leave a comment

On July 21, the Institute for International Trade and the School of Economics will host a public lecture at the University of Adelaide by leading trade economist Professor Iwan Azis on the topic of “Trade agreements in a second-best world”. The lecture will examine the challenges and issues that nations face in negotating trade agreements in a less-than-perfect […]

Posted in Economic research, Events, Institue for International trade, International trade, Public policy
Leave a comment

At the SA Centre for Economic Studies’ Economic Briefing Luncheon this week, the Centre’s Deputy Director Steve Whetton, gave an excellent overview of the SA, Australian and global economies. Steve’s slides are available here.

Posted in Business economics, Economic growth, Economic research, Paul Kerin, South Australian Centre for Economic Studies, South Australian economy
Leave a comment